G
reen
Innovations can further be categorised into ‘frontier
innovations’ i.e. new-to-the-world innovations and ‘catch-up
innovations’ which comprise of diffusion (both across and within
countries) and their adaptation to existing green products, processes,
organisational and marketing technologies. Thus combining the
understanding of innovation in the context of development and what is
widely understood as ‘green’1, ‘green
innovation’ can be defined as different ways that support and enable
wealth creation and achieve more resource-efficient, clean and resilient
growth. Examples of these range from technologies that improve energy
efficiency, resource efficiency (e.g. Vertical Shaft Brick Kilns, hollow
bricks), production processes (e.g., cement industry using municipal
waste as a source of fuel, fly ash bricks), design and planning (e.g.
urban land use design, industrial symbiosis) etc.
As the above examples suggest, ‘green innovation’ can
to a large extent influence the green growth agenda. Dutz and Sharma
(2012), in their paper titled, ‘Green Growth, Technology and Innovation’
speak of a ‘double externality’, i.e., of knowledge-related market
failures that have a compounding effect on the environmental
externalities.
To develop an understanding of the term ‘double
externality’, it is first essential to identify the different mechanisms
of innovation. These comprise of direct government funding for research
and development (R&D) which includes funding of public labs and
universities, grants, soft loans and R&D tax subsidies to private firms
for early-stage, pre-commercialisation technology development. These are
referred to as supply-push mechanisms that allow for coordinated
research with little or no duplication.
In contract to supply-push mechanism for innovation,
there are demand-pull mechanisms, for example patents and prize funds.
Patents are essentially decentralised self- selected mechanisms
where those involved believe that they are most likely to succeed and
thus risk their resources for the ‘prize of a period of exclusivity’
during which product prices are set and the disclosure of knowledge is
restricted to other researchers. On the other hand, a prize fund
refers to a pre-announced prize which is given to the creators of any
innovation that meets defined objectives. Prize funds are considered
most relevant mechanisms to promote technologies at the global level for
the needs of countries with lower technological capabilities and less
developed economies.
The above mechanisms are suggestive of various R&D
policy instruments as drivers of long-term innovation. However, these
R&D policies applied on their own are said to result in ‘double
externalities’. A classic externality problem in the production of
knowledge, is that the benefits to society from the particular
innovation, may exceed the private benefits from producing it (Schmidt,
Hansen, Tops, Jensen, & Jespersen, 2010). Thus, what is evident is that
the investments made are often not sufficient in comparison to the
societal gains they create, which results in a ‘missing price’. While
the ‘missing price’ refers to a negative externality, the benefits to
the society as well as to the environment, refer to the positive
externality or the positive spill-overs, thus the term double
externality.
Green Innovation and the Indian Green Growth Agenda
Research has shown that a significant proportion of
frontier green innovation takes place in high-income countries, with
Japan, Germany and US accounting for 60 % of the total green innovation
worldwide. Between 2000 and 2005, these majorly comprised of greenhouse
gas mitigation technologies. Developing countries have a large capacity
for catch-up green innovation through new-to-the firm adoption and
adaptation of existing green technologies and through indigenous
base-of-pyramid innovation (Dutz & Sharma, 2012).
Base-of-pyramid innovations are defined as
innovations to meet the needs of poor consumers. These innovations
include formal innovations for the poor, primarily those by global and
local private companies, public institutions, supported by public
subsidies or produced through public-private partnerships. They also
include informal innovations by local grassroots innovators which are
based on improvisation and experimentation. These innovations aim at
meeting the needs of poor households at affordable costs and at scale.
Hence these innovations seek to create more products with less resources
for a larger audience.

Thus both catch-up green innovation and
base-of-pyramid innovation provide developing countries like India,
who have lower technological capabilities to direct their green
innovation policy agenda needs to take into account their local
environmental needs, technological sophistication and implementation
capabilities. A survey conducted on green base-of pyramid innovations by
Dutz (2012) indicates that there continue to be very few green
base-of-pyramid innovations that have been sufficiently scaled up.
Further it is crucial to revisit the concept of
double externality that suggests that that there is no single
solution to solve both innovation and environmental challenges. Green
innovation policies require to better understand both supply and demand
side constraints, barriers to scaled-up commercialisation, identify the
benefit-cost of particular policies and their implementation to improve
market outcomes. It is often realised that a single innovation policy
may lead to the rebound effect. That is to say that a single R&D
policy could drive consumer demand towards supporting a technology that
lowers the cost of energy used per unit, hence leading consumers to
respond by increasing their level of energy consumption. This is called
the rebound effect.
Innovation policies in developing countries like in
India, need to put in place policy instruments that are able to address
the complementary knowledge and environment-related market failures. The
optimal combination of policies include both an incentive to stimulate
innovation towards influencing more sustainable growth (R&D subsidy that
directs technical change towards cleaner technology) and a separate
environmental incentive to internalise the pollution externality. This
could be in the form of an emission tax or specific targets. Thus a
combination of technology and environmental policies can facilitate the
creation and diffusion of new environmentally-friendly technologies,
while complementary policies ensure that the environmental externality
is corrected through stronger incentives for their creation and adoption
(Dutz & Sharma, 2012).
Key Recommendations
As is implied previously, the promotion of green
growth for most developing countries is largely in the form of catch-up
innovation and the diffusion of already existing technologies and lesser
in the form of frontier innovation. While developing countries like
India do not have the technological capabilities for the creation of
frontier innovation, it can neither deny that fact that cost of not
adopting, adapting and using existing green technologies can be high in
terms of impeding a greener development pathway. Thus innovation
policies in India should aim at ensuring removal of existing distortions
and weaknesses in the business environment that hinders private
innovation, especially through adoption of more open foreign trade,
investment and technology licensing regimes, improve access to finance,
strengthen skills and capacity development and implement greater
demand-side policies like public procurement, regulations and standards.
While there are numerous policy mixes that can enable diffusion and
adoption of green technologies, the fact that remains is that there is
lack of reliable data on the number of green base-of-pyramid innovations
and the evaluation of the impact of these technologies in meeting the
needs of the poor consumers. Thus, experimental evaluation with
randomised controlled trials and quiz-experimental evaluation of
existing technologies will require to be the first steps in identifying
the appropriate mix of policies for a greener growth trajectory through
the application of effective innovation policies. ■
Pratibha Ruth Caleb
pcaleb@devalt.org
Endnotes
1 Referring
to environmental sustainability
References:
1. Dutz, M. A., & Sharma, S. (2012). Green Growth, Technology and
Innovation. The World Bank.
2. Schmidt, S. N., Hansen, E. S., Tops, J., Jensen, H. N., & Jespersen,
S. T. (2010). Innovation of Energy Technologies: the role of taxes.
Copenhagen: European Commission.
Back to Contents